Bounded Rational Reciprocal Preference Relation for Decision Making
Abstract
Fuzzy relations have been widely applied in decision making process. However, the application process requires people to have a high level of ability to compute and infer information. As people usually have limited ability of computing and inferring, the fuzzy relation needs to be adapted to fit the abilities of people. The bounded rationality theory holding the view that people have limited rationality in terms of computing and inferring meets such a requirement, so we try to combine the fuzzy relation with the bounded rationality theory in this study. To do this, first of all, we investigate four properties of fuzzy relations (i.e. reflexivity, symmetry, transitivity and reciprocity) within the bounded rationality context and find that these properties are not compatible with the bounded rationality theory. Afterwards, we study a new property called the bounded rational reciprocity of fuzzy relations, to make it possible to combine a fuzzy relation with the bounded rationality theory. Based on the bounded rational reciprocity, the bounded rational reciprocal preference relation is then introduced. A rationality visualization technique is proposed to intuitively display the rationality of experts. Finally, a bounded rationality net-flow-based ranking method is presented to solve real decision-making problems with bounded rational reciprocal preference relations, and a numerical example with comparative analysis is given to demonstrate the advantages of the proposed methods.
1Introduction
The fuzzy relation (Zadeh, 1971) uses a membership degree to represent the degree that one ordering pair belongs to a relation. Compared with the binary relation, the membership degree of a fuzzy relation belongs to
Usually, the determination of a fuzzy preference relation requires people to have enough skills in particular aspects. For instance, the fuzzy preference ordering requires people to obey the property of transitivity. The weak transitivity means that, if A is better than B and B is better than C, A should be better than C. Constructing a fuzzy preference ordering needs people to have the perfect ability of computing and inferring data. There are technologies to repair the fuzzy preference ordering which does not obey the transitivity (Saaty, 1977). These technologies force people to make changes on preference information but could not reflect the limited reasoning capacity and knowledge of people. In economic and management realms, the traditional postulate of economic man requires experts to have high or even complete rationality (i.e. the perfect ability of computing and inferring) (Simon, 1955). However, in practice, because of the limitation of human cognition and computation ability, it is difficult for a person to reach the global rationality. To tackle this problem, Simon (1955) proposed the bounded rationality theory, aiming to give a reasonable explanation of human’s real behaviour from the aspects of cognition and psychology. The bounded rationality theory explains rather than restricts human behaviour, and the results of models based on the bounded rationality theory are in line with the real situations of human society (Huang et al., 2013). The bounded rationality theory has also been applied in probability models (Uboe et al., 2017; Le Cadre et al., 2019) and fuzzy decision-making models (Wang and Fu, 2014; Wu and Zhao, 2014; Angus, 2016). The bounded rationality theory does not require people to have a high ability of computing and inferring. Therefore, this paper considers to combine the fuzzy preference relation with the bounded rationality theory. Given that the development of a fuzzy preference relation was based on four properties including reflexivity, symmetry, transitivity, and reciprocity (which will be explained in detail in Section 2), we need to investigate whether the four properties are in line with the bounded rationality theory.
In this study, the usability of the four properties of a fuzzy preference relation is firstly discussed under the bounded rationality situation. It is found that all four properties do not satisfy the bounded rationality. Because the transitivity might be violated in real decision-making problems (Świtalski, 2001) and it is a problem to select a suitable definition of transitivity from a group of definitions of transitivity (Zadeh, 1971; Wang, 1997; Herrera-Viedma et al., 2004), we try to improve the definition of reciprocity. Then, a new property called the bounded rational reciprocity is proposed. Based on the new property, the bounded rational reciprocal preference relation is introduced. A rationality visualization technique and a bounded rationality net-flow-based ranking method are presented to help people apply the bounded rational reciprocal preference relation to solve real decision-making problems.
The contributions of this study are highlighted as follows:
(1) We introduce the bounded rational reciprocity. Since the reflexivity, symmetry, transitivity, and reciprocity do not suit the bounded rationality theory, we propose the rationality value to define a new property called the bounded rational reciprocity. Compared with the transitivity and reciprocity, the bounded rational reciprocity explains rather than restricts the membership degree, which reduces the difficulty of collecting information and improves the flexibility of decision making.
(2) The bounded rational reciprocal preference relation is proposed to model the limited ability of people. By combining the idea of the bounded rational reciprocity and fuzzy preference relation, we introduce the bounded rational reciprocal preference relation. The rationality radius is presented to explain experts’ rationality. The rationality visualization technique is introduced to intuitively display the rationality of experts.
(3) A bounded rationality net-flow-based method is presented to rank alternatives in decision-making problems. With the weights of experts, the aggregated bounded rational reciprocal preference relation is calculated. The positive and negative bounded rationality flow is introduced to get the bounded rationality net flow, which can be further used to rank alternatives. A numerical example is given to demonstrate the bounded rationality net-flow-based decision-making method. Comparative analyses with the reciprocal preference relation and non-reciprocal preference relation are given to show the advantages of the proposed decision-making method.
This study is organized as follows: In Section 2, we review the bounded rationality theory and fuzzy preference relation. In Section 3, the bounded rational reciprocity and bounded rational reciprocal preference relation are proposed. Section 4 introduces the rationality visualization technique and the bounded rationality net-flow-based ranking method. A numerical example is also given in Section 4. Section 5 closes the paper with concluding remarks.
2Preliminaries
For the convenience of presentation, in this section, the relevant theories are introduced.
2.1Fuzzy Relation and Its Developments
To analyse the incompatibility between fuzzy preference relations and the bounded rationality, this section introduces the fuzzy preference relation and its developments. We begin with the concept of binary relation.
For two sets of evaluations on alternatives x and y,
In the above Example 1, if we know that
For fuzzy relations, they have four properties, namely, reflexivity, symmetry, transitivity, and reciprocity (Zadeh, 1971; Bezdek et al., 1978). The reflexivity means
Different combinations of these four properties yielded different developments of the fuzzy relation. These developments could be divided into two categories. Regarding the first group, Zadeh (1971) proposed a few concepts which mainly focused on transitivity, symmetry, and reflexivity. The fuzzy ordering was the fuzzy relation having transitivity. The fuzzy preordering was the fuzzy ordering having reflexivity. The similarity relation was the fuzzy preordering satisfying the symmetry. The fuzzy partial ordering was the fuzzy preordering which was anti-symmetric. The fuzzy linear ordering was the fuzzy partial ordering satisfying
Fig. 1
Among the developments of fuzzy relations, the fuzzy preference ordering attracted the attention of many researchers. Different kinds of uncertainty were considered to improve the fuzzy preference ordering. Xu (2007) proposed the intuitionistic preference relation considering the membership and non-membership degrees. Liao et al. (2014) introduced the hesitant fuzzy preference relation which could express experts’ hesitancy degrees. There were triangular fuzzy reciprocal preference relation (Meng et al., 2017) in which the membership function was a triangular fuzzy number and interval fuzzy preference relation (Meng et al., 2019) using intervals to express uncertainty. Zhang et al. (2019) presented the q-rung orthopair fuzzy preference relation to deal with the problems that the membership degree plus non-membership degree is larger than 1. Gong et al. (2020) proposed the linear uncertain preference relation. The use of fuzzy relations in decision making facilitated its developments in theory (Wan et al., 2017; Ferrera-Cedeño et al., 2019; Zhang et al., 2021). Known from Section 2.2., experts are usually bounded rational. However, as far as we know, few studies discussed the suitability of the four properties within the context of bounded rationality.
2.2Bounded Rationality Theory
In the traditional economic theory, there is a postulate of economic man, that experts are familiar with, who has related knowledge and a stable system of preference (Simon, 1955). This economic man postulate requires experts to have high rationality, and thus it is also called the global rationality postulate (Simon, 1955). The postulate of economic man simplifies the analysis of real problems by mathematical models. In real situations, especially in economic and management realms, practical issues might be complex. Usually, an expert is only proficient in one or two areas. Facing practical issues that involve many areas like the law and marketing, experts might not have enough knowledge, which causes the cognitive limitation of experts. Besides, experts’ computation ability is limited. When there is a large amount of data, experts might not be able to process the whole data, resulting in the weak estimation of the result of a decision. Because the cognition levels of experts are limited by their knowledge, it is hard for them to satisfy the global rationality postulate. In this situation, the simplification of real problems by the postulate of economic man might cause unreasonable results.
To make the postulate of economic man compatible with experts’ abilities, Simon (1955) first proposed the concept of bounded rationality. Different from the global rationality postulate which restricts human behaviours, the bounded rationality theory aims to give a reasonable explanation for experts’ realistic behaviours from the aspects of human cognition and psychology. To achieve this goal, decision processes and methods were simplified from the perspective of the gross characteristics of human choice (Simon, 1955) and the broad features of the environment (Simon, 1956). A few interesting notions, such as the satisfactory solutions (Simon, 1955), were proposed based on the bounded rationality theory.
Motivated by the bounded rationality theory, a mass of researches has been done, which can be grouped into two categories. The first group considered probability models with the bounded rationality theory. Mattsson and Weibull (2002) reviewed the development of the game theory with the bounded rationality and proposed a probabilistic choice model with bounded rationality. Sterman et al. (2007) combined the bounded rationality theory with disequilibrium dynamics to create a dynamic behavioural game model. Huang et al. (2013) used a special queue model, where customers’ waiting time cannot be accurately estimated, to capture the bounded rationality, and concluded that if the bounded rationality was ignored, there was a “significant revenue and welfare loss”. The second group focused on the fuzzy theory. Angus (2016) found that, in addition to the probability theory, it was also necessary to consider the fuzzy theory together with the bounded rationality theory. Wang and Fu (2014) used a nonlinear scalarization technique to model bounded rationality in generalized abstract fuzzy economies. Wu and Zhao (2014) proposed the fuzzy choice functions of fuzzy preference relations under the circumstance of bounded rationality. Chang et al. (2019) considered the transitivity of fuzzy preference relations with bounded rationality and proposed the triangular bounded consistency of fuzzy preference relations. Furthermore, the bounded rationality theory has achieved several applications in terms of organization management (Simon, 1991), transportation system design (Cascetta et al., 2015), stock management (Sterman, 1989), policy advice (Caballero and Lunday, 2020), hotel selection (Wang et al., 2020), and the analysis of customers’ behaviours in service operations systems (He et al., 2020).
For the existing researches on fuzzy preference relations under the bounded rationality circumstance (Wang and Fu, 2014; Wu and Zhao, 2014), the core idea was to use formulas and constraints to express the bounded rationality, which was similar to Lipman’s idea (1991). However, they ignored a key problem that the original properties of fuzzy preference relations might not be compatible with the bounded rationality. This incompatibility might cause systematic and inherent errors when using existing methods (Wang and Fu, 2014; Wu and Zhao, 2014). In Section 3, we will further analyse this incompatibility in detail.
3Bounded Rational Reciprocal Preference Relation
As mentioned in Section 2.1, few studies investigated the four properties of fuzzy relations within the context of bounded rationality. If the four properties are not compatible with the bounded rationality theory, the applications of fuzzy relations might be limited in practice. In this section, we begin with the discussion on the question whether the four properties are compatible with the bounded rationality. It is found that all four properties do not satisfy the bounded rationality theory. Thus, a new property called the bounded rational reciprocity is proposed. Then, the bounded rational reciprocal preference relation is introduced based on the bounded rational reciprocity.
3.1Whether the Properties of Fuzzy Relation are in Line with the Bounded Rationality Theory?
Different relations “R” have different rules of reflexivity. When the relation “R” is “equal or better”, the reflexivity can be
The symmetry means that the membership degree of
There is a mass of rules concerning transitivity which requires experts to have a stable preference system (Zadeh, 1971; Wang, 1997; Herrera-Viedma et al., 2004; Chang et al., 2019). On one hand, an empirical study has pointed out that experts’ preferences might violate the transitivity (Świtalski, 2001), so the transitivity might not be necessary. On the other hand, different experts might have different reasoning processes, so the fixed transitivity might restrict experts’ behaviours. This restriction is also not in line with the bounded rationality theory.
3.2Bounded Rational Reciprocal Preference Relation with the Bounded Rational Reciprocity
According to the analyses in Section 3.1, it is clear that the four properties are not compatible with the idea of the bounded rationality theory. Motivated by the idea of the reciprocal index (Dong et al., 2008), we propose a new property satisfying bounded rationality.
Most of the time,
Definition 1.
For two alternatives
For a fuzzy relation, the membership degree
Transitivity was usually used to judge experts’ rationality. If the preference did not satisfy the transitivity, some consistency adjustment methods (Herrera-Viedma et al., 2004; Jin et al., 2020) were proposed to modify the given preference information. These studies held the view that the preference dissatisfying the transitivity was irrational, so the change was necessary. However, experts might have their special transitivity property even though their preference information does not satisfy certain transitivity. In other words, this does not mean that the experts are irrational (Karapetrovic and Rosenbloom, 1999).
Compared with the transitivity and reciprocity, the bounded rational reciprocity tries to explain rather than restrict membership degrees. As the bounded rational reciprocity does not limit the value of
Because the reflexivity, symmetry, transitivity and reciprocity do not satisfy the bounded rationality, the existing preference relations reviewed in Section 2.2 are not compatible with the bounded rationality theory. Because the bounded rational reciprocity, which is in line with the bounded rationality theory, has superiorities in decision making, we propose the bounded rational reciprocal preference relation based on the bounded rational reciprocity.
Definition 2.
For a given alternative set
The bounded rational reciprocal preference relation on an alternative set
In practical decision-making processes, experts may have different understandings about different alternatives, causing various
Example 1.
For a given alternative set
The developments of fuzzy relations based on the reciprocity, like the fuzzy preference ordering (Tanino, 1984), cannot express the data in Example 1. Because the bounded rational reciprocal preference relation does not have the constrain
3.3A Rationality Visualization Technique to Display the Rationality of Experts
The membership degrees in the bounded rational reciprocal preference relation can be represented by the triples
For all pairs
However, in the 3D coordinate system, the midpoints are not easy to be visually distinguished, so it is necessary to make a transformation. Let
Example 2.
The matrix in Example 2 is marked in a 3D coordinate system in Fig. 2.
Fig. 2
In Fig. 2(a), there is a point which represents that the membership degree of
Fig. 3
4Decision Making Based on the Bounded Rational Reciprocal Preference Relation
To use the bounded rational reciprocal preference relation in order to solve decision-making problems, we propose a bounded rationality net-flow-based method to rank alternatives.
4.1A Bounded Rationality Net-Flow-Based Ranking Method for Decision Making
Before proposing the bounded rationality net-flow-based ranking method, we first make a description of the decision making framework. There are n alternatives denoted by
If the rationality of expert
(1)
Then, k bounded rational reciprocal preference relations can be aggregated to an aggregated bounded rational reciprocal preference relation
For alternatives
(2)
For an alternative
(3)
Theorem 1.
Proof.
For any
4.2A Numerical Example
This section gives a numerical example to illustrate the bounded rationality net-flow-based ranking method. Suppose that three experts
In
Fig. 4
From Fig. 4, it is easy to find that the second expert
By Eq. (2), the weights of alternative pairs are
4.3Comparative Analysis with the Net-Flow-Based Ranking Method Using Reciprocal Preference Relations
In this section, we make a comparative analysis to demonstrate the advantages of the bounded rationality net-flow-based ranking method and the bounded rational reciprocal preference relations.
We use the aggregated bounded rational reciprocal preference relation
Then, we use the net flow to rank the alternatives (Fodor and Roubens, 1994). The positive flows of the three alternatives
The result here is the same as the ranking obtained in Section 4.2, which indicates that the result of the bounded rationality net-flow-based ranking method is reliable. Compared with the bounded rational reciprocal preference relation, the reciprocal preference relation requires to do the translations when dealing with practical data. As mentioned by Yager and Alajlan (2017), the use of the parameter q might cause the loss of information. Besides,
4.4Comparative Analysis with the Multi-Stage Decision-Making Method Using Non-Reciprocal Preference Relations
Parreiras et al. (2012) proposed a non-reciprocal preference relation with a multi-stage decision-making method. Here, the weights used to integrate experts’ preference information were given by experts. Suppose that the weights of the three experts are
After that,
Afterwards, we remove
In the non-reciprocal preference relation (Parreiras et al., 2012), one of
Compared with the bounded rationality net-flow-based ranking method, the multi-stage decision-making method here is time-consuming because it decides only one alternative at one stage. Besides, the weights in the multi-stage decision-making method are given by the decision-maker, which are not objective. For the multi-stage decision-making method, a small change on weights might influence the final ranking. For instance, if we do a small change on the weights
From the comparative analyses in Section 4.3 and Section 4.4, we can get the following advantages of the bounded rationality net-flow-based ranking method and the bounded rational reciprocal preference relations:
– Compared with the reciprocal preference relation, the bounded rational reciprocal preference relation does not need to change the original preference information when expressing the information given by experts.
– In the non-reciprocal preference relation, one of the membership and non-membership degrees should be 0 or 1, which has restrictions on preference relations. On the contrary, the bounded rational reciprocal preference relation allows experts to give preference information without restrictions, so it is convenient for experts to give the preference information in the bounded rational reciprocal preference relation.
– Compared with the multi-stage decision-making method, the bounded rationality net-flow-based ranking method can get the final ranking of alternatives with one computation.
4.5Ranking Reversals in the Bounded Rationality Net-Flow-Based Ranking Method
The ranking reversal says that when we add an alternative to the decision making problem, the ranking of the previous alternatives might be reversed (Belton and Gear, 1983). Here, we find that the ranking reversal also occurs in the bounded rationality net-flow-based ranking method. For example, continued to Section 4.2, after adding an alternative with random data to the problem, the new bounded rational preference relations are shown as
Using the bounded rationality net-flow-based ranking method, the final ranking is
5Conclusion
The four properties of fuzzy relations (i.e. reflexivity, symmetry, transitivity, and reciprocity) were not compatible with the bounded rationality theory. In this regard, the rationality value and rationality radius were introduced in this paper to explain experts’ rationality levels. Then, the bounded rational reciprocity of fuzzy relations was proposed. Based on this property, the bounded rational reciprocal preference relation, which can explain the rationalities of experts, was defined. A rationality visualization technique and a bounded rationality net-flow-based ranking method were given to help experts in using the bounded rational reciprocal preference relation. Comparative analysis showed the advantages of the bounded rational reciprocal preference relation and the bounded rationality net-flow-based ranking method.
There are still some unsolved issues. This paper focuses on the theory study of the bounded rational reciprocal preference relation. The reasonableness of the proposed theory needs to be certified by practical examples. The bounded rational reciprocal preference relation can be considered in other multiple criteria decision-making methods. Moreover, how to avoid the ranking reversals in the bounded rationality net-flow-based ranking method is an interesting research question that can be investigated in the future.
References
1 | Angus, D.C. ((2016) ). Defining sepsis: a case of bounded rationality and fuzzy thinking. American Journal of Respiratory and Critical Care Medicine, 194: , 14–15. https://doi.org/10.1164/rccm.201604-0879ED. |
2 | Belton, V., Gear, T. ((1983) ). On a shortcoming of Saaty’s method of analytic hierarchies. Omega, 11: (3), 228–230. https://doi.org/10.1016/0305-0483(83)90047-6. |
3 | Bezdek, J.C., Spillman, B., Spillman, R. ((1978) ). A fuzzy relation space for group decision theory. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 1: , 255–268. https://doi.org/10.1016/0165-0114(78)90017-9. |
4 | Caballero, W.N., Lunday, B.J. ((2020) ). Robust influence modeling under structural and parametric uncertainty: an Afghan counternarcotics use case. Decision Support Systems, 128: , 113161. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.dss.2019.113161. |
5 | Cascetta, E., Cartenì, A., Pagliara, F., Montanino, M. ((2015) ). A new look at planning and designing transportation systems: a decision-making model based on cognitive rationality, stakeholder engagement and quantitative methods. Transport Policy, 38: , 27–39. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tranpol.2014.11.005. |
6 | Chang, W.J., Fu, C., Xu, D.L., Xue, M. ((2019) ). Triangular bounded consistency of fuzzy preference relations. Information Sciences, 479: , 355–371. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ins.2018.12.029. |
7 | Dong, Y.C., Li, H.Y., Xu, Y.F. ((2008) ). On reciprocity indexes in the aggregation of fuzzy preference relations using the OWA operator. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 159: , 185–192. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.fss.2007.06.010. |
8 | Ferrera-Cedeño, E., Acosta-Mendoza, N., Gago-Alonso, A., García-Reyes, E. ((2019) ). Detecting free standing conversational group in video using fuzzy relations. Informatica, 30: (1), 21–32. https://doi.org/10.15388/Informatica.2019.195. |
9 | Fodor, J., Roubens, M. ((1994) ). Fuzzy Preference Modelling and Multicriteria Decision Support. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-017-1648-2. |
10 | Gong, Z.W., Gou, W.W., Herrera-Viedma, E. ((2020) ). Consistency and consensus modeling of linear uncertain preference relations. European Journal of Operational Research, 283: , 290–307. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2019.10.035. |
11 | He, Q.C., Chen, Y.J., Righter, R. ((2020) ). Learning with projection effects in service operations systems. Production and Operations Management, 29: , 90–100. https://doi.org/10.1111/poms.13093. |
12 | Herrera-Viedma, E., Herrera, F., Chiclana, F., Luque, M. ((2004) ). Some issues on consistency of fuzzy preference relations. European Journal of Operational Research, 154: , 98–109. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0377-2217(02)00725-7. |
13 | Huang, T., Allon, G., Bassamboo, A. ((2013) ). Bounded rationality in service systems. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 15: , 263–279. https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.1120.0417. |
14 | Jin, F., Pei, L., Liu, J., Zhou, L.G., Chen, H.Y. ((2020) ). Decision-making model with fuzzy preference relations based on consistency local adjustment strategy and DEA. Neural Computing and Applications, 32: , 11607–11620. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00521-019-04648-1. |
15 | Karapetrovic, S., Rosenbloom, E.S., ((1999) ). A quality control approach to consistency paradoxes in AHP. European Journal of Operational Research, 119: , 704–718. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0377-2217(98)00334-8. |
16 | Le Cadre, H., Mezghani, I., Papavasiliou, A. ((2019) ). A game-theoretic analysis of transmission-distribution system operator coordination. European Journal of Operational Research, 274: , 317–339. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2018.09.043. |
17 | Liao, H.C., Xu, Z.S., Xia, M.M. ((2014) ). Multiplicative consistency of interval-valued intuitionistic fuzzy preference relation. Journal of Intelligent & Fuzzy Systems, 27: (6), 2969–2985. |
18 | Lipman, B.L. ((1991) ). How to decide how to decide how to...: modeling limited rationality. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 59: , 1105–1125. https://www.jstor.org/stable/2938176. |
19 | Mattsson, L.G., Weibull, J.W. ((2002) ). Probabilistic choice and procedurally bounded rationality. Games and Economic Behavior, 41: , 61–78. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0899-8256(02)00014-3. |
20 | Meng, F.Y., Lin, J., Tan, C.Q., Zhang, Q. ((2017) ). A new multiplicative consistency based method for decision making with triangular fuzzy reciprocal preference relations. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 315: , 1–25. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.fss.2016.12.010. |
21 | Meng, F.Y., Tang, J., Fujita, H. ((2019) ). Consistency-based algorithms for decision-making with interval fuzzy preference relations. IEEE Transactions on Fuzzy Systems, 27: , 2052–2066. https://doi.org/10.1109/TFUZZ.2019.2893307. |
22 | Nakamura, K. ((1986) ). Preference relations on a set of fuzzy utilities as a basis for decision making. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 20: , 147–162. https://doi.org/10.1016/0165-0114(86)90074-6. |
23 | Orlovsky, S.A. ((1978) ). Decision-making with a fuzzy preference relation. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 1: , 155–167. https://doi.org/10.1016/0165-0114(78)90001-5. |
24 | Parreiras, R., Ekel, P., Bernardes, F. Jr. ((2012) ). A dynamic consensus scheme based on a nonreciprocal fuzzy preference relation modeling. Information Sciences, 211: , 1–17. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ins.2012.05.001. |
25 | Saaty, T.L. ((1977) ). A scaling method for priorities in hierarchical structures. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 15: , 234–281. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-2496(77)90033-5. |
26 | Simon, H.A. ((1955) ). A behavioral model of rational choice. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 69: , 99–118. https://doi.org/10.2307/1884852. |
27 | Simon, H.A. ((1956) ). Rational choice and the structure of the environment. Psychological Review, 63: , 129–138. https://doi.org/10.1037/h0042769. |
28 | Simon, H.A. ((1991) ). Bounded rationality and organizational learning. Organization Science, 2: (1), 125–134. https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.2.1.125. |
29 | Sterman, J.D. ((1989) ). Modeling managerial behavior: misperceptions of feedback in a dynamic decision making experiment. Management Science, 35: , 321–339. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.35.3.321. |
30 | Sterman, J.D., Henderson, R., Beinhocker, E.D., Newman, L.I. ((2007) ). Getting big too fast: strategic dynamics with increasing returns and bounded rationality. Management Science, 53: , 683–696. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1060.0673. |
31 | Świtalski, Z. ((2001) ). Transitivity of fuzzy preference relations-an empirical study. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 118: , 503–508. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0165-0114(98)00287-5. |
32 | Tanino, T. ((1984) ). Fuzzy preference orderings in group decision making. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 12: , 117–131. https://doi.org/10.1016/0165-0114(84)90032-0. |
33 | Uboe, J., Andersson, J., Jornsten, K., Lillestol, J., Sandal, L. ((2017) ). Statistical testing of bounded rationality with applications to the newsvendor model. European Journal of Operational Research, 259: , 251–261. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2016.10.007. |
34 | Wan, S.P., Wang, F., Dong, J.Y. ((2017) ). Additive consistent interval-valued Atanassov intuitionistic fuzzy preference relation and likelihood comparison algorithm based group decision making. European Journal of Operational Research, 263: , 571–582. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2017.05.022. |
35 | Wang, L., Fu, Y. ((2014) ). Bounded rationality of generalized abstract fuzzy economies. The Scientific World Journal, 2014: , 347579. https://doi.org/10.1155/2014/347579. |
36 | Wang, L., Wang, X.K., Peng, J.J., Wang, J.Q. ((2020) ). The differences in hotel selection among various types of travellers: a comparative analysis with a useful bounded rationality behavioural decision support model. Tourism Management, 76: , 103961. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tourman.2019.103961. |
37 | Wang, X.Z. ((1997) ). An investigation into relations between some transitivity-related concepts. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 89: , 257–262. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0165-0114(96)00104-2. |
38 | Wu, X.L., Zhao, Y. ((2014) ). Research on bounded rationality of fuzzy choice functions. The Scientific World Journal, 2014: , 928279. https://doi.org/10.1155/2014/928279. |
39 | Xu, Z.S. ((2007) ). Intuitionistic preference relations and their application in group decision making. Information Sciences, 177: , 2363–2379. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ins.2006.12.019. |
40 | Yager, R.R., Alajlan, N. ((2017) ). Approximate reasoning with generalized orthopair fuzzy sets. Information Fusion, 38: , 65–73. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.inffus.2017.02.005. |
41 | Zadeh, L.A. ((1971) ). Similarity relations and fuzzy orderings. Information Sciences, 3: , 177–200. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0020-0255(71)80005-1. |
42 | Zhang, C., Liao, H.C., Luo, L. ((2019) ). Additive consistency-based priority-generating method of q-rung orthopair fuzzy preference relation. International Journal of Intelligent Systems, 34: , 2151–2176. https://doi.org/10.1002/int.22137. |
43 | Zhang, S.L., Tang, J., Meng, F.Y., Yuan, R.P. ((2021) ). A group decision making method with interval-valued intuitionistic fuzzy preference relations and its application in the selection of cloud computing vendors for SMEs. Informatica, 32: (1), 163–193. https://doi.org/10.15388/20-INFOR416. |